Monopoly Power

in #monopoly2 months ago


Image Source

Monopoly Power: What Should We Fear?

This week’s assigned reading is a speech titled “Monopoly Power: What Should We Fear?” presented by Dr. Per Bylund. He begins by defining a monopoly as a market with only one seller. He highlights how it’s easy to dislike monopolies, yet when we try to examine the specifics, it’s hard to pinpoint exactly why they are bad. He argues that monopoly power is acceptable in certain contexts. I haven’t ever considered the potential positives of monopolies.

Innovation and Monopolies

His first point is that innovators creating new markets technically monopolize what they produce. While monopolies do mean the market has no alternative sellers, consumers still have the option of not buying the product in the first place. He references Steve Jobs and how Apple initially had a monopoly over smartphones. Customers had the option to refrain from buying the iPhone or to choose a typical phone instead. Dr. Bylund emphasizes that no one forces consumers to purchase a product and that they always have the option to buy something else if they prefer. Additionally, he states that Apple had to innovate to compete with the flip phone market and, in doing so, became a monopoly. This example highlights the positive side of monopolies that arise from innovation. However, I believe that it overlooks how monopolies, once established, can leverage their dominance to create artificial barriers for future competitors, even in the absence of direct regulation.

Consumer Power

He points out that power is often cited as the main concern when discussing monopolies. For example, he references Nokia and how the company had to create a better product to outperform competitors and become the dominant player in the market. He argues that innovators who create a new market have no extra power or control over consumers, as their success depends on the value they provide. Someone asked what happens if a monopoly raises prices considerably. Dr. Bylund contends that rather than monopolies draining consumers’ money indefinitely, other companies would likely enter the market and offer a similar product at a cheaper price. Essentially, he asserts that the real issue is when no one else can enter the market. If companies cannot compete due to artificial barriers, that is the true problem—not the monopoly itself. He concludes that any barrier to entry into a market constitutes monopoly power. In some industries, significant capital investment, technical expertise, or brand loyalty can create de facto barriers to entry, even without formal regulations. I believe some of what he says is easier said than done.

Student Questions

One student asked Dr. Bylund for his thoughts on antitrust laws. He responded by pointing out the irony of governments enacting regulations to break up monopolies while simultaneously imposing laws that can create barriers to market entry. Instead, he argues, there should be fewer restrictions to enable more competition. As an example, he cites Uber and Lyft, which disrupted the taxi monopoly by offering new solutions to consumers. He emphasizes that a company’s success is not determined by its size but by the value it provides to its customers. Another student asked about companies buying out smaller competitors in their markets. Dr. Bylund argues that these acquisitions typically occur because the smaller company is being offered value for their business—otherwise, the deal wouldn’t happen. A student then asked about politicians being paid to pass favorable regulations for specific companies. Dr. Bylund notes that such practices result in money being wasted on lobbying and campaigning rather than on innovation. I find this a compelling point against monopolies. One of Dr. Bylund’s key points is that businesses often favor regulations because these rules protect them from new competitors, which creates the real power of monopolies. Dr. Bylund’s critique of regulatory capture is particularly insightful. However, it could be extended to explore how lobbying and campaign contributions often lead to sustained monopolistic advantages, such as tax breaks, subsidies, or exclusionary policies, which undermine his claim that innovation alone drives monopolies.

Conclusion

Dr. Bylund's argument that monopolies are not inherently harmful is thought-provoking, especially his emphasis on how innovation often creates temporary monopolies that drive progress. His point that barriers to entry are the real source of concern is compelling, as restrictive regulations and policies can stifle competition and innovation. Additionally, his example of Uber and Lyft breaking the taxi monopoly effectively illustrates how open competition is important and benefits consumers. However, even in the absence of regulatory barriers, companies with significant market dominance can limit consumer choice through exclusivity agreements which can create an unfair playing field for smaller businesses.